10. COMMUNITY UPLIFTMENT—WOULD A LEGAL TRADE HELP RHINOS AND PEOPLE?

Would an open, well-regulated, legal horn market draw new investment into breeding rhinos and would this help not only the species but provide opportunities for local communities as well?

Photo credit: Shannon Wild

NO TRADE

Africa and Asia’s prime wildlife regions are mostly adjacent to impoverished rural communities. This applies globally and as much in Asia as it does in Africa. For these local people to embrace a custodianship or stewardship ethic with regard to wildlife and its management, they have to derive benefit from it. Universally, conservation has at best had a checkered career in this regard.

The potential profitability of rhino farming certainly looks like an attractive option for local communities. But the assumptions of potential returns are predicated on market conditions panning out the way pro-traders imagine would be the case. The scenario of a demand constantly met by supply at an attractively high price may not prevail. The point is made time and time again that we have little understanding of potential market dynamics in the context of a legal trade.

Certainly there are successful instances of domesticating wild animals for ranching. It is after all a process that has been ongoing for thousands of years. Crocodile and ostrich farming are frequently cited as good examples. But both these animals are rapid and prolific breeders, which is not the case with rhinos.

And there have been failures too. Vicuñas, for example, were once the poster child of wildlife trade protagonists. But while the initial legal trade in their wool did lead to a population increase, poaching and the illegal trade are again threatening the species.

Like most farming enterprises, start-up rhino breeders would require substantial capital. Not only would there be the cost of acquiring initial breeding stock, rhinos born into farming operations would take just as long as wild rhinos to reach an age and horn size big enough to be harvested – five years or more. That is a long time to bear costs without a return.

And it’s not just the cost of initial stock. The cost of security fences and systems, veterinary costs, and food would be incurred some time before profits from harvesting would come.

Who would fund the start-up cost of establishing new farmers, particularly community farmers? Charitable donations may help to fund pilot projects, but not great numbers of newcomers.

The high projected returns from legally sold horn might be attractive to potential investors, but they only hold if the assumptions around a legal trade prove to be correct.

Maybe Asian governments would become invested in a legal trade, but not necessarily in ways that would support African and potentially Indian breeders. It might simply be more profitable for Asian investors  to set up their own farms and cut out farmers in range countries. In an open trade environment, they would be entitled to do so. The investment capital would not be an issue and it would be easy enough to source breeding stock.

PRO TRADE

There is no questioning the fact that the prosperity and quality of life of communities living alongside wildlife reserves is of paramount importance. For conservation areas to succeed, these rural communities have to derive every meaningful benefit possible from participating in their care.

An example of this working well in practice is in northwest Namibia, where formal rhino conservation began in the early 1980s and innovative conservancy models evolved to place local people, and their values, at the center of solutions geared more towards stopping poaching than catching poachers. The objective was to make poaching a socially unacceptable act and, with jobs and revenue connected to rhinos, to create an environment in which community members would be far more likely to report suspicious circumstances in an effort to protect rhino that are seen as belonging to the community.

There is no reason not to breed rhinos for the renewable harvest of their horns. The fact that there are already collectively some 6,300 rhinos on privately owned property in South Africa, proves that substantial herds can be grown. So why not embrace this opportunity? After all, there are plenty of instances where the domestication and farming of once wild animals has worked: crocodile and ostrich farming for instance, and the ranching of a number of antelope species. Crocodile farming is a major international industry – a million crocodile skins are traded annually, exported legally from about 30 countries across the world – South Africa, Zimbabwe and Kenya are major producers. 

A controlled legal trade should encourage other landowners, both individuals and communities, to start breeding rhinos and to enter a market that would potentially deliver income some 100 times that of traditional livestock farming. This need not mean the wholesale conversion of livestock ranching to rhino breeding as it is possible to manage both activities side by side.

Part of the revenue earned by new rhino breeders would go towards paying rangers and anti-poaching teams and other farm workers market-related salaries. Such employment opportunities would go a long way to gaining the support of rural communities.

Furthermore, by becoming active market participants, state reserves, private landowners, and communities with rhinos would be able to generate a substantial income from these animals, which are at present regarded as a massive financial burden.

 

And if Asian governments become invested in the legal trade, which they could be through taxation and even directly, they would have an incentive to help close down the illegal trade.